Production Possibility Frontier.W1

Production Possibility Frontier.W1


2024年5月11日发(作者:魅蓝e3屏幕)

Microeconomics – Week 1. Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)

tion Possibility Frontier (PPF)

Under the field of macroeconomics, the production possibility frontier (PPF) represents the point

at which an economy is most efficiently producing its goods and services and, therefore, allocating

its resources in the best way possible. If the economy is not producing the quantities indicated by the

PPF, resources are being managed inefficiently and the production of society will dwindle. The

production possibility frontier shows there are limits to production, so an economy, to achieve

efficiency, must decide what combination of goods and services can be produced.

Let's turn to the chart below. Imagine an economy that can produce only wine and cotton. According

to the PPF, points A, B and C - all appearing on the curve - represent the most efficient use of

resources by the economy. Point X represents an inefficient use of resources, while point Y

represents the goals that the economy cannot attain with its present levels of resources.

As we can see, in order for this economy to produce more wine, it must give up some of the

resources it uses to produce cotton (point A). If the economy starts producing more cotton

(represented by points B and C), it would have to divert resources from making wine and,

consequently, it will produce less wine than it is producing at point A. As the chart shows, by moving

production from point A to B, the economy must decrease wine production by a small amount in

comparison to the increase in cotton output. However, if the economy moves from point B to C, wine

output will be significantly reduced while the increase in cotton will be quite small. Keep in mind that

A, B, and C all represent the most efficient allocation of resources for the economy; the nation must

decide how to achieve the PPF and which combination to use. If more wine is in demand, the cost of

increasing its output is proportional to the cost of decreasing cotton production.

Microeconomics – Week 1. Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)

Point X means that the country's resources are not being used efficiently or, more specifically, that

the country is not producing enough cotton or wine given the potential of its resources. Point Y, as

we mentioned above, represents an output level that is currently unreachable by this economy.

However, if there were changes in technology while the level of land, labour and capital remained

the same, the time required to pick cotton and grapes would be reduced. Output would increase, and

the PPF would be pushed outwards. A new curve, on which Y would appear, would represent the

new efficient allocation of resources.

When the PPF shifts outwards, we know there is growth in an economy. Alternatively, when the PPF

shifts inwards it indicates that the economy is shrinking as a result of a decline in its most efficient

allocation of resources and optimal production capability. A shrinking economy could be a result of a

decrease in supplies or a deficiency in technology.

An economy can be producing on the PPF curve only in theory. In reality, economies constantly

struggle to reach an optimal production capacity. And because scarcity forces an economy to forgo

one choice for another, the slope of the PPF will always be negative; if production of product A

increases then production of product B will have to decrease accordingly.

2. Opportunity Cost

Opportunity cost is the value of what is foregone in order to have something else. This value

is unique for each individual. You may, for instance, forgo ice cream in order to have an extra

helping of mashed potatoes. For you, the mashed potatoes have a greater value than dessert. But

you can always change your mind in the future because there may be some instances when the

mashed potatoes are just not as attractive as the ice cream. The opportunity cost of an individual's

decisions, therefore, is determined by his or her needs, wants, time and resources (income).

This is important to the PPF because a country will decide how to best allocate its resources

according to its opportunity cost. Therefore, the previous wine/cotton example shows that if the

country chooses to produce more wine than cotton, the opportunity cost is equivalent to the cost of

giving up the required cotton production.

Let's look at another example to demonstrate how opportunity cost ensures that an individual will

buy the least expensive of two similar goods when given the choice. For example, assume that an

individual has a choice between two telephone services. If he or she were to buy the most expensive

service, that individual may have to reduce the number of times he or she goes to the movies each

month. Giving up these opportunities to go to the movies may be a cost that is too high for this

Microeconomics – Week 1. Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)

person, leading him or her to choose the less expensive service.

Remember that opportunity cost is different for each individual and nation. Thus, what is valued

more than something else will vary among people and countries when decisions are made about

how to allocate resources.

3. Trade, Comparative Advantage and Absolute Advantage

Specialisation and Comparative Advantage

An economy can focus on producing all of the goods and services it needs to function, but this may

lead to an inefficient allocation of resources and hinder future growth. By using specialization, a

country can concentrate on the production of one thing that it can do best, rather than dividing up its

resources.

For example, let's look at a hypothetical world that has only two countries (Country A and Country B)

and two products (cars and cotton). Each country can make cars and/or cotton. Now suppose that

Country A has very little fertile land and an abundance of steel for car production. Country B, on the

other hand, has an abundance of fertile land but very little steel. If Country A were to try to produce

both cars and cotton, it would need to divide up its resources. Because it requires a lot of effort to

produce cotton by irrigating the land, Country A would have to sacrifice producing cars. The

opportunity cost of producing both cars and cotton is high for Country A, which will have to give up a

lot of capital in order to produce both. Similarly, for Country B, the opportunity cost of producing both

products is high because the effort required to produce cars is greater than that of producing cotton.

Each country can produce one of the products more efficiently (at a lower cost) than the other.

Country A, which has an abundance of steel, would need to give up more cars than Country B would

to produce the same amount of cotton. Country B would need to give up more cotton than Country A

to produce the same amount of cars. Therefore, County A has a comparative advantage over

Country B in the production of cars, and Country B has a comparative advantage over Country A in

the production of cotton.

Now let's say that both countries (A and B) specialize in producing the goods with which they have a

comparative advantage. If they trade the goods that they produce for other goods in which they don't

have a comparative advantage, both countries will be able to enjoy both products at a lower

opportunity cost. Furthermore, each country will be exchanging the best product it can make for

another good or service that is the best that the other country can produce. Specialization and trade

also works when several different countries are involved. For example, if Country C specializes in

the production of corn, it can trade its corn for cars from Country A and cotton from Country B.

Determining how countries exchange goods produced by a comparative advantage ("the best for the

best") is the backbone of international trade theory. This method of exchange is considered an

optimal allocation of resources, whereby economies, in theory, will no longer be lacking anything that

they need. Like opportunity cost, specialization and comparative advantage also apply to the way in

which individuals interact within an economy.

Absolute Advantage

Sometimes a country or an individual can produce more than another country, even though

countries both have the same amount of inputs. For example, Country A may have a technological

advantage that, with the same amount of inputs (arable land, steel, labour), enables the country to

manufacture more of both cars and cotton than Country B. A country that can produce more of both

goods is said to have an absolute advantage. Better quality resources can give a country an

absolute advantage as can a higher level of education and overall technological advancement. It is

not possible, however, for a country to have a comparative advantage in everything that it produces,

so it will always be able to benefit from trade.


发布者:admin,转转请注明出处:http://www.yc00.com/num/1715409507a2613821.html

相关推荐

发表回复

评论列表(0条)

  • 暂无评论

联系我们

400-800-8888

在线咨询: QQ交谈

邮件:admin@example.com

工作时间:周一至周五,9:30-18:30,节假日休息

关注微信